האוניברסיטה העברית בירושלים

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "האוניברסיטה העברית בירושלים"

Transcription

1 האוניברסיטה העברית בירושלים THE HEBREW UNIVERSITY OF JERUSALEM ON THE PREFERENCE FOR FULL-COVERAGE POLICIES: WHY DO PEOPLE BUY TOO MUCH INSURANCE? by ZUR SHAPIRA and ITZHAK VENEZIA Discussion Paper # 460 August 2007 מרכז לחקר הרציונליות CENTER FOR THE STUDY OF RATIONALITY Feldman Building, Givat-Ram, Jerusalem, Israel PHONE: [972] FAX: [972] ratio@math.huji.ac.il URL:

2 On the preference for Full-Coverage policies: Why do people buy too much insurance? by Zur Shapira Stern School of Business New York University and Center for the Study of Rationality Hebrew University, Jerusalem and Itzhak Venezia School of Business Hebrew University, Jerusalem August 10, 2007 Financial support from the Galanter foundation, The Zagagi Center of Finance, The Center of Accounting at the Hebrew university, The Sanger Family Chair for Banking and Risk Management, the Stern School of Business, and the Whitcomb Center for Research in Financial Services at Rutgers University are gratefully acknowledged. We also thank Yehuda Kahane and the College of Insurance in Tel Aviv for support in data collection. We are grateful for the insightful comments of an anonymous referee. We also acknowledge comments by seminar participants at the Center for Experimental Social Sciences at NYU, and at the School of Management, Yale University, as well as the comments of David Backus, Maya Bar-Hillel, Sari Carp, David Levine, Jeffrey Simonoff and Rodelle A. Williams.

3 On the preference for Full-Coverage policies: Why do people buy too much insurance? Abstract One of the most intriguing questions in insurance is the preference of consumers for low or zero deductible insurance policies. This stands in sharp contrast to a theorem proved by Mossin, 1968, that under quite common assumptions when the price of insurance is higher than its actuarial value, then full coverage is not optimal. We show in a series of experiments that amateur subjects tend to underestimate the value of a policy with a deductible and that the degree of underestimation increases with the size of the deductible. We hypothesize that this tendency is caused by the anchoring heuristic. In particular, in pricing a policy with a deductible subjects first consider the price of a full coverage policy. Then they anchor on the size of the deductible and subtract it from the price of the full coverage policy. However, they do not adjust the price enough upward to take into account the fact that there is only a small chance that the deductible will be applied toward their payments. We also show that professionals in the field of insurance are less prone to such a bias. This implies that a policy with a deductible priced according to the true expected payments may seem overpriced to the insured and therefore may not be purchased. Since the values of full coverage policies are not underestimated the insured may find them as relatively better deals. 2

4 On the preference for Full-Coverage policies: Why do people buy too much insurance? I. Introduction In a seminal paper, Mossin (1968) showed that under quite common assumptions, fullcoverage insurance is not optimal. More precisely, he demonstrated that if the price of insurance is proportional to but higher than the expected payments made by the insurer and if the insured is risk averse, then full coverage is sub-optimal for the insured. He also showed that there exists a policy with a strictly positive deductible, which dominates the full-coverage policy. Mossin s normative logic stands in contrast to the high demand for full-coverage policies and policies with very low deductibles. For example, almost all liability insurance policies provide full coverage or a zero deductible. Consider also collision damage insurance for rental cars. While specific rates vary by location, a typical collision damage waiver (CDW) for a rental car costs on average $25 per day, which is equal to $7200 on an annual basis. In stark contrast, comprehensive automobile insurance for one s own car does not cost more than $1000 per year in most locations in the U.S. The difference in price is clearly nontrivial. Why are people willing to pay such high rates for CDW when renting a car? Another example arises from deductibles on automobile insurance policies. The deductible on automobile insurance is often as low as $100 and almost always below $500, which means that consumers are insured against losses of $500 or less. Cummins and Weisbart (1978) report that when Herbert Denenberg, Pennsylvania s Insurance Commissioner during the 1970s, tried to raise the minimum auto insurance deductible from $50 to $100, he was forced to withdraw this idea by massive consumer outcry. Merchants who sell various electrical products such as cell phones costing $200 or less also offer insurance against loss, for a non-trivial additional cost. Consumer purchases of such 3

5 insurance do not seem to be rational even when those policies include a service component. Companies offering such warranty in their service policies stand to make a high profit due to such consumer preferences. According to a Harvard Business School case (see Burns, 2004), to a first approximation Circuit City sold electronics at cost and made its profits on extended warranties. The situation is even more salient in medical insurance. For example, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reports that during the years , 34% percent of full time employees in the private sector enrolled in non-hmo medical care organizations had no deductibles in their medical plans. This percentage rose to 42% for Preferred provider organizations (U.S. Department of Labor, 1999). Note also that HMOs typically have zero deductibles. An attempt to explain the preference for full coverage was offered by Pashigian, Schkade, and Menefee (1966), who used U.S. aggregate data as well as detailed data of automobile insurance purchases in Missouri. They found that the levels of deductibles chosen by clients are too low to be explained by expected utility theory. According to Pashigian et. al. these deductibles can be reconciled with expected utility only if the insureds anticipate two or more accidents per year. This figure is considerably higher than the number of accidents actually expected by the average driver. Pashigian et. al. conclude that: the observed selection of deductibles can be explained [only] if there is a systematic tendency to overestimate the objective probabilities of an accident greater than the deductible. (p.40). In light of the difficulty of standard utility theory to explain the demand for low deductibles, Ben-Arab, Briys, and Schlesinger (1996) try to explain excessive insurance purchasing by assuming a multi-period habit-formation utility function. This type of utility function introduces a greater desire to smooth consumption over time than a usual one-period 4

6 utility. It therefore gives rise to a higher incentive for insurance purchasing, and tolerance of lower deductibles. Wakker, Thaler and Tversky (1997) argue that people buy too much insurance since they are averse to probabilistic insurance. Such behavior is not consistent with expected utility maximization. Other researchers such as Braun and Muermann (2004), explain it by aversion to regret. 1 Schoemaker (1976) demonstrates that when faced with decisions described as insurance against hypothetical losses, subjects chose full coverage alternatives over those with deductibles. Nonetheless, when the same choices were framed as lotteries, their choice pattern was reversed. 2 Schoemaker s findings imply that framing affects the way people evaluate insurance alternatives. Likewise, in an elaborate experimental design, Johnson, Hershey, Meszaros and Kunreuther (1993) find that students preferred insurance alternatives framed as rebates rather than as policies with a deductible. Framing clearly affects the way people make choices among insurance alternatives, but there may be other factors at play when people evaluate the monetary value of alternative insurance policies. In this paper, we provide a new explanation based on the anchoring heuristic for the preference for full coverage and test it experimentally. 3 We argue that the price of a full coverage policy is a natural starting point for evaluating a policy with a deductible. Insureds continue from this starting point and calculate the price of policies with partial coverage by anchoring on the value of the deductible. In anchoring on the amount itself they neglect to take into account the probabilities associated with actual damages. Since they do not adjust for the probability that damage will actually occur, they end up underestimating the price of such policies. Insurance 1 In personal communications we had, the issue of regret came up very often. Many people expressed the idea that they will have hard time convincing their spouses that they would save money over their life time when they have to pay a high deductible. The extent to which such arguments affect decisions has not been empirically determined however. 2 In a somewhat related study, Slovic et. al. (1977) demonstrate that (contrary to utility theory s explanation of insurance) small expected damage, coupled with a high probability, is seen as more troubling than high expected damage with a small probability of occurring, which has the same expected value. 3 For a definition of anchoring see Tversky and Kahneman (1974) and Mullainathan and Thaler, (2001). 5

7 companies are unlikely to make such errors and hence the prices they set for policies with a deductible may seem unjustifiably high to customers. On the other hand insureds are less likely to underestimate the values of full coverage policies, and hence they may deem such policies as more adequately priced then the partial coverage policies offered by the insurance companies, and hence prefer them to policies with a deductible. We used insurance sellers as subjects in the experiments reported in this paper. We assumed that insurance sellers would pay more attention to pricing decisions than buyers would pay to their purchasing decisions. The reason is that sellers need to think of both their potential customers as well as their competitors in making their decisions. However, we have no reason to expect sellers to be less prone to biases such as to the anchoring heuristic, unless they have had some real experience in selling insurance policies in the past. Research on the insurance behavior of both buyers and sellers indicate that biases in terms of probability assessment that were found in studies of insurance in the context of natural disasters as early as 1977 (see Kunreuther et. Al., 1977) still persist today. 4 We conducted three experiments to test our hypothesis. In all these experiments, we asked subjects to play the role of insurance sellers and to price policies with and without a deductible. They competed with other sellers and their objective was to set prices so as to maximize their profits. We compare the prices the subjects set relative to the true expected damages under each policy. We argue that if individuals underestimate the value of a policy with a deductible, the prices they set for policies with a deductible would be low relative to the expected damages covered under full coverage policies. In the first two sets of experiments, 4 Viscusi and Zeckhauser (2006) report that in the aftermath of Hurricane Katrina the majority of a nationally representative sample of respondents in the U.S. underestimated their risks from all hazards and judged them to be below average with only a third of the sample estimating their risks as average. 6

8 subjects were amateur insurance consumers, and in the third the subjects were professionals in the field of insurance. In all contexts, subjects were requested to price a policy of full coverage and a policy with a specific deductible (D = 100 in the first and third experiment, D=60 or D=120 in the second experiment). The paper is structured as follows. In the next section, we review some of the basic relevant theory: Mossin s theorem on the one hand, and literature on anchoring on the other. In Section III-V we present the experiments. The first experiment, presented in Section III, used Israeli MBA students as subjects. In Section IV we present the results of the second experiment, which is similar to the first experiment with two variations. First, we added an American sample of MBA students as a test of the generalizability of the results across countries. Second, instead of a single policy with a deductible, we split the sample and presented each group with a different deductible to allow a stronger test of our hypothesis about the effect of anchoring. Section V presents the results of the third experiment, in which professionals in the field of insurance were the subjects. Section VI concludes. II. Theoretical Background Anchoring effects on pricing policies with a deductible Several studies have shown that when considering the purchase of insurance policies, people do not behave in a rational manner (see, e.g., Kunreuther et. al. 1977) and that their choices are affected by framing (Johnson et. al, 1993). Shapira and Venezia, (1999) show that subjects do not calculate expected damages properly. 5 Granted, at times the evaluation of a policy with a deductible may not be easy. A person renting a car may find it difficult to determine what is covered by his own insurance provider and/or by her credit card company. In 5 Shapira and Venezia, (1999) also show in similar experimental studies that subjects do not tend to use deductibles for screening purposes. 7

9 such a situation, paying for a few days of collision damage insurance may not seem too expensive and simplifies the decision. As Kahneman and Tversky (1979) reasoned, the unattractiveness of probabilistic insurance is related to the desire of people to insure against worries rather than against actual damages. Their discussion highlights the difficulty to conceive of the potential situations that may arise if one doesn t have full coverage. Consequently, full coverage policies provide an anchor for thinking about insurance problems because such policies are easy to envision and the need to calculate expected damages is reduced. When offered a menu of policies with different deductibles, people may find it convenient to think about policies with small deductibles; these are close in price to a full coverage policy. With high deductibles, people may exhibit a bias that emanates from the anchoring heuristic (cf. Tversky and Kahneman, 1974), that is, in estimating what would be a reasonable price for a policy with a deductible, they often anchor on the deductible amount itself, subtract it from the price of the full coverage policy and in setting the price of the policy with the deductible they do not adjust the price enough upwards to take into account the fact that actual damage amounts are probabilistic. Thus, we hypothesize that as the deductible increases in value, people anchor on it and their estimate of a reasonable price of such a policy departs to a larger degree than is warranted from the price of the full coverage policy. III. Study 1: Pricing of policies with one deductible level (amateurs) Subjects: Eighty-five MBA students enrolled in a course in risk management and insurance at the Hebrew University and at the Tel Aviv branch of Manchester University, whose age ranged from 21 to 29 participated in the Experiment. Prior to taking the course and participating in the experiment, the students completed several courses in economics and statistics, and at least one course in finance. The students were told that they would receive a 8

10 bonus towards their grade based on the profits they generated in the experiment. Specifically, they were told that the top 2%, 5%, and 10% students with the highest profits would receive respectively 4,2,1 points, respectively, toward their final grade (on a 100- point scale). Since the students were highly motivated by grades, there rewards were quite attractive. Method: The task facing the subjects was framed in the context of selling renter insurance policies and is described in Table 1. Subjects were requested to determine prices Insert Table 1 about here for two possible policies, one providing full coverage, (i.e., a zero deductible, D=0), denoted FC and the other, denoted D (with a deductible D = $100). They could have also elected to price only one policy or none at all. We explained how deductibles work, and reminded them that lower prices induce higher demand, but are less likely to cover losses and provide a profit. We carefully explained to the subjects that their decisions would enter into a simulated market. The clients in the simulated market have damages and claims as described in Table 1. Subjects were told that based on their prices, the prices of the competitors (which were the other subjects in the experiment), and the decisions of the simulated clients, we would compute profits for each of them. The students were told that the demand was not perfectly elastic, that lower prices would attract higher demand, but that the lowest price would not attract all customers. The profits were calculated as the difference between total revenues (the number of policies sold of each type multiplied by their respective prices) and total claims (simulated by using the number of clients of each type who bought each policy, and their distribution of claims). Each subject made his/her decision on their own and no communication among subjects was allowed. 9

11 Our analysis consists of comparing the prices set by the subjects with the true expected values of payments under the policies. We examine whether there is mis-pricing, and if mispricing is more common in policies with a deductible than in the full coverage policies. 6 In order to make profits in this game subjects had to set prices higher than the expected payments. They would set prices lower than the expected payments only if they underestimate these payments. Thus one part of the analysis consists of comparing mis-pricing of the full coverage policies, if any, with mis-pricing of the non zero deductible policies. To better understand the nature of the bias in pricing policies with a deductible we compared the prices of policies with and without deductibles. We hypothesize that the policy with a deductible is evaluated by starting with the value of the full coverage policy and then adjusting for the deductible. A correct adjustment is to subtract the expected value of deductible non-payments from the value of a full coverage policy reduce. If the deductible is $100 and the probability of damage is 10%, then the correct adjustment is $10 ($100 X 0.1). A possible error in evaluating a policy with a deductible stems from calculating its value by subtracting the deductible from the value of a full coverage policy that is, by subtracting the full $100 rather than its expected value, which yields a gross underestimate of the expected payments. To determine how prevalent this type of error is we counted the number of subjects for whom the difference in price was larger than or equal to the deductible. If the subjects did not err in the calculation, the difference should have been closer to the expected value of the payments they would not receive because of the deductible. Results and discussion: Table 2 presents the summary statistics of the pricing of all policies for Experiment 1. We present the average price, P, the maximum price, and the 6 Risk aversion could also affect pricing. Since our subjects are sellers who price policies for many clients, this should not affect them directly. They can take into account the risk aversion of their clients; however risk aversion with respect to the loss of a deductible is trivial as the amount at risk is small. 10

12 minimum price determined for the two policies the subjects were required to price: policy FC (full coverage, or 0 deductible), and policy D (with a $100 deductible). We then present in this table the expected payments, E, the insurers (subjects) would have to make to the insureds under each type of policy. Based on these variables, we calculated the expected profitability ratio EPR (P/E), that is, the average price relative to expected payments Insert Table 2 about here The expected profitability ratios exhibited by the subjects provide an indication of the under-valuation of the policies with a deductible. Note that the average expected profitability ratio of the policies with a deductible is less than 1 showing that they are under-priced, whereas the average expected profitability ratio for the full coverage policy is higher than 1 (See Table 2). The under-pricing of the policies with a deductible is quite pronounced. The average expected profitability ratio is 1.13 for the full coverage policy compared with 0.64 for the policy with the deductible. Assuming that subjects set prices so as to at least cover their costs, these expected profitability ratios imply that on average subjects undervalued the expected payments they had to make under the deductible policies by at least 36%. In contrast to such striking under-valuation of the policies with a deductible, the prices of the full coverage policies were more in line with expected payments as the expected profitability ratio is about 13% above 1. This suggests that subjects seriously underestimated the expected payments under the policies with a deductible. To demonstrate the undervaluation of the policies with a deductible in yet another way, we calculate the proportion of subjects who priced this policy for less than the expected damages, E D. A large proportion, 67%, priced policies with a deductible at less than the expected damages. In contrast, the proportion of subjects who priced the full coverage policy by less than 11

13 the expected payments under that policy is only 20%, indicating that subjects are much more likely to underestimate the value of a policy with a deductible than to underestimate a full coverage policy. We observe the following common error in valuation. Subjects calculated expected payments under the policy with a deductible by computing first the payments of the full coverage policy, and then subtracting the deductible of $100. This led them to underestimate the expected payments since only the expected non-payments of the deductible should have been subtracted from the value of the full coverage policy. To demonstrate how pervasive this error was, we calculated the proportion of subjects for whom the difference in price between the full coverage and the deductible policy, P, was at least $100 (that is, equal or larger than the deductible). We observe from Table 2 that for about 45% of the subjects, the price of the full coverage policy exceeded that of the policy with the deductible by $100 or more. The difference in expected payments between the two policies is, however, only $20. IV. Study 2: Pricing policies with different deductibles (amateurs) The purpose of this study was to test the effect of anchoring on the pricing of a policy with different levels of a deductible. We hypothesize that people begin their calculation with the price of the full coverage policy and then anchor on the amount of the deductible without adjusting enough. Thus, the larger the deductible, the more pronounced is the effect of the misadjustment. Subjects: The subjects were 39 practicing managers who were enrolled in an executive MBA program in a northeastern university. Their ages ranged from 28 to 45. By the time they participated in the experiment, they have had several courses in economics and finance. 12

14 Method: The method was a replication of the method used in experiment 1 with two changes. First, the subjects were divided into two groups and the amount of the deductible varied by group. It was $60 for the first group and $120 for the second. In addition, two monetary awards were announced in each group. These were a $50 Barnes and Noble gift certificate for purchasing books for the winner and $25 for the runner up. These two prize categories were announced (and later awarded) in each group. Results and discussion: Summary statistics of the pricing of all policies are presented in Table 3. The main results are similar to those of experiment 1. As in the previous experiment we find that the difference between the prices of the deductible policies and the full coverage are much higher than those justified by the difference in expected values. For the group with D=60 (D=120) the difference in price between the full coverage and the policy with a deductible is (117) whereas the difference between the expected values of payments of these policies is only 18 (32). This shows that both groups over-charge for full coverage. Note however, that the lower deductible group overcharges around 100 % for eliminating the deductible (they add to the price for increasing the expected payments by 18). The higher deductible group overcharges by 265% (they add 117 to the average price for increasing payments by 32). We also find, as hypothesized, higher measures of mis-pricing to the group with the higher deductible. This can be observed from Panel B of Table 3. Note also that a higher percentage of subjects in this group priced the policy with a deductible by subtracting the deductible from the full coverage. The percentage of subjects for whom the difference in price between the full coverage and the deductible policy is larger than or equal to D, is 55.6% for the group with D = 120 as compared to 23.8% for the group with the lower (D=60) deductible (See 13

15 Table 3). The group with the higher deductible also has as a higher percentage of subjects underpricing the deductible policy (55.6% vs. 47.6%), but not the full coverage policy Insert Table 3 about here In addition to asking the subjects for the prices they would set, we asked them to write down their calculation and the reasons for the particular prices they set for the policies. Their responses provide support for our hypothesis about anchoring on the deductible without sufficient adjustment. Several subjects in the higher deductible condition wrote down their calculation where they literally subtracted the deductible from the price of the full coverage policy price. One subject wrote: To make a profit on the full coverage policy, according to my calculations I will charge $280. Accordingly, I will charge $180 for the $100 deductible policy. Another subject wrote that since in the $0 deductible policy the expected payout is $140, I will charge a 20% markup and set a price of $168. For the $120 policy, the expected payout is $20 and with a 10% markup I will charge $22 for it. A subject in the low deductible condition wrote: To cover the cost of the full coverage policy I need to charge $140. This price is not competitive though. We know that 70% of the market incurs no claims, and 20% incur small claims. Therefore, I would discount the price to 80% of the initial price and charge $112. For deductibles with $60, I would charge $80. Finally, a couple of subjects commented in their responses that no one will buy the $120 deductible policy but many will buy the $0 deductible one. Note that we did not test whether the subjects in our experiments were profit maximizers, We were just trying to determine whether the subjects were prone to the anchoring bias. They were rewarded according to the profits they made so there is no reason to assume that they would have set prices that would harm their profits. Some of the subjects, mainly those who proved to 7 These measures of mis-pricing are not independent, however. 14

16 be prone to the anchoring bias, lost money because of this predisposition. However, from the subjects' written answers and explanations about the calculations they made we are able to infer that they were using a cost-plus strategy and tried to maximize their profits. Unfortunately for those who miscalculated the probabilities due to the anchoring bias, this strategy ended in losses. V. Study 3: Pricing of policies by professionals Subjects: All 26 subjects participating in this study were insurance practitioners, ranging in age from 30 to 55 years and possessing at least 5 years of experience in the industry. Their job titles included insurance agent, supervisor of insurance agents, underwriter, and owner of an insurance agency. The subjects were enrolled in classes at the College of Insurance in Tel-Aviv, Israel, pursuing advanced courses in Insurance. They completed the task during the first 30 minutes of a regular class session. Method: The method essentially replicated the method of the first experiment. Results and discussion: The results are presented in Table Insert Table 4 about here The table displays the same statistics as Tables 2 and 3. In the case of the professionals, policies with a deductible are not as underestimated (if underestimated at all) as in the case of amateurs. The average expected profitability ratio of the policies with the deductible are well above 1 although lower than the average expected profitability ratio for the full coverage policies. The difference between the average expected profitability ratio of the full coverage policies and the deductible policies is.20 ( ) for the professionals as compared with.49 ( ) for the amateurs (See Tables 4 and 2 respectively). Pricing of the policies below the expected payments was also less common among professionals. Only about 27% priced 15

17 deductible policies lower than the expected value, as compared with 67% of the amateurs. The proportions of subjects for whom the difference in price between the full coverage and the deductible policy is larger than or equal to 100 is smaller among the professionals, 31.8%, as compared with 45 % for the amateurs. This indicates that although some professionals made the same evaluation error as the amateurs, this phenomenon is much less pervasive among the professionals. Observing that the professional sellers seem to be "more rational" it is interesting to explore whether and how they could exploit their superior knowledge. Even if the sellers expect the buyers to underestimate the expected damages associated with a policy with a deductible, they would never set a price for a policy with an EPR < 1, since such prices would lead them to losses. Suppose however that not all buyers are homogeneous and asymmetric information between sellers and buyers exists about the risk level of the buyers. The sellers could then, under certain circumstances, use this knowledge to attract the lower risk customers. They could device a menu of contracts, some with a deductible and one of full coverage all with an EPR > 1 that would induce buyers to self select; the lower risk individuals would select contracts with a deductible and the higher risk buyers will choose the full coverage contract. 8 VI. General discussion Our results show that amateurs tend to underestimate the value of policies with a deductible. This bias occurs because subjects are inclined to estimate the value of such policies by calculating the value of an equivalent full coverage policy, and then subtracting the deductible. In this case, the higher the deductible, the higher the under-valuation of the policy. This bias emanates from subjects tendency to anchor on size of the deductible without adjusting 8 We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this argument but defer a fuller analysis of this line of reasoning to future research as it is outside the scope of this paper. 16

18 enough. The findings suggest that in purchasing insurance policies subjects behavior is affected by the anchoring heuristic (Chapman and Johnson, 2002; Kahneman, 1992), which leads consumers to purchase insurance with low or no deductibles. According to Epley and Gilovich (2006) the anchoring literature deals either with a "phenomenon" (namely, estimates gravitate toward an anchor) or with a "process" where people adjust their final estimates from an initial anchor. They further argue that true insufficient adjustments occur when people adjust insufficiently from values they "generate themselves as starting points from values known to be incorrect but close to the target value." (p. 312). The authors claim that such self-generated anchors help simplify the complex cognitive process involved in making judgments. Along these lines, it appears that our subjects might have gone through a similar process. They were not provided with an anchor but the amount of deductible was construed by them as a good enough estimate for the price of a policy with a deductible even though they did not verify that it was the correct value. It definitely helped them come up with a plausible value without engaging in an effortful evaluation and they figured out that the error, if existed, could not be substantial. We also find that in comparison with amateurs, professionals are less likely to exhibit the above bias. Professionals are likely to value and price deductible policies correctly (i.e., according to the true expected payments), whereas the general public (amateurs) may find the prices the professionals set for policies with a deductible to be too high compared with their own underestimated expected payments. Note that the professionals in our studies had a similar academic background to that of the amateurs. Yet, the professionals experience helped them perform better than the amateurs in the present quantitative experimental setting. Possibly, the 17

19 professionals experience in the field minimizes the tendency to anchor on the deductible when evaluating policies with deductibles. The preference of subjects for low deductibles is often interpreted as an indication of high-risk aversion. Our results suggest that such behavior can also result from cognitive biases. One may argue that such a bias may not have significant effects on market behavior since the more sophisticated insurance sellers may eventually lead the market to a more rational equilibrium. The truth may actually be the opposite. Even if professional insurance sellers are (relatively) immune from this bias, the fact that amateur consumers are affected by it has direct implications since two sides are needed for market transactions. A real life example can illustrate this argument. During the time we ran one of the experiments, the Direct Insurance Corporation, one of the largest insurance companies in Israel advertised insurance rates for car owners. The advertised rates for policies with different levels of deductible for a $30, Toyota Corolla, for drivers whose age was 25 or higher, are displayed in Table Insert Table 5 about here We used those publicly advertised rates and circulated a survey among MBA students enrolled in a graduate course on Risk management and insurance at the Hebrew University. We asked the students to indicate what level of coverage they would choose if they had a car of a similar value and were offered those rates. Forty three students responded to the survey. Twenty two of them (51%) chose the lower three levels of deductible. Note that in raising the deductible from $137 to $180, an increase of $43, the insured saves $35. Practically, unless the insured is certain that he or she will have an accident, or is extremely risk averse; the lower deductible is not a highly valued alternative. By increasing the deductible from $180 to $245, an increase of 18

20 $65, the insured saves $42; again unless there is a very high probability of an accident (71%), the higher deductible is more reasonable. We do not have data on the percentage of insureds that buy policies at each level of deductible from the Direct Insurance Company, but it is reasonable to assume that if the insurer advertised this price list, there was demand for all those deductibles. The fact that the insureds in our sample failed to comprehend the implications of the alternatives presented to them has direct market implications. It also complements other studies where investors made costly mistakes, such as in the study of Benartzi and Thaler, (2002). Our findings have some ramifications both from the point of view of consumer groups and from the perspectives of regulators in the insurance industry. In the Benartzi and Thaler, (2002) study investors appear not to have well defined preferences as their choices depend on irrelevant alternatives, and hence intervention in this market may be desirable. Whereas in their study the bias is due to framing, in our experiments as in Choi, Laibson, Madrian, and Metrick, (2004), the bias stemmed from anchoring. A similar argument has been proposed by Gneezy, List and Wu (2006) who showed that in certain situations subjects preferred the worst outcome of a lottery over the lottery itself. They attribute their finding to the uncertainty effect and claim that in certain situations of uncertainty people tend to discount lotteries for uncertainty in a manner similar to the one we discussed above. Finally, the current findings may also be useful in analyzing behavior in other areas where high risk aversion is invoked as an explanation, such as the issue of the risk premium puzzle (Mehra and Prescott, 1985, 2003). Future research should examine whether bounded rationality and computational limitations can further our understanding of behavior in other financial puzzles. 19

21 References Ben-Arab, Mounira, Briys, Eric and Harris Schlesinger, (1996). Habit formation and the demand for insurance. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 63, Benartzi, Shlomo, and Richard Thaler, (2002), How Much Is Investor Autonomy Worth? The Journal of Finance, 57, Braun, Michael and Alexander Muermann, (2004), "The Impact of Regret on the Demand for Insurance. Journal of Risk and Insurance 71, Burns, William, (2004). Circuit city stores, Inc. Harvard Business School, Case no Chapman, Gretchen. and Eric Johnson, (2002). Incorporating the irrelevant: Anchors in judgments of belief and value. In Gilovich, T. Griffin, D. and D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and Biases: The psychology of Intuitive Judgment. New York: Cambridge University Press. Choi, James, David Laibson, James, Madrian, Brigitte and Andrew Metrick, (2004) For Better or For Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior. In David Wise editor Perspectives in the Economics of Aging. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Cummins, David, and S. Weisbart, (1978). "The impact of consumer services on independent insurance agency performance." Glenmont, NY: IMA Education and Research Foundation. Epley, Nicholas and Thomas Gilovich, (2006), "The anchoring and adjustment heuristic: Why the adjustments are insufficient." Psychological Science, 17, Gneezy, Uri, List, John, and George Wu, (2006), The uncertainty effect: When a risky prospect is valued less than its worst outcome. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, Johnson, Eric, Hershey, John, Meszaros, Jacqueline and Howard Kunreuther, (1993). Framing, 20

22 probability distortion and insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7, Kahneman, Daniel. (1992). Reference points, anchors, norms and mixed feelings. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 51, Kahneman, Daniel. and Tversky, Amos. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under Risk. Econometrica, 47, Kunreuther, Howard et al. (1978). Disaster Insurance. New York: Wiley. Mehra, Rajnish and Edward Prescott, (1985). The Equity Premium: A Puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 15, Mehra, Rajnish and Edward Prescott, (2003). The Equity Premium in Retrospect. NBER Working Paper No Mossin, Jan, (1968). Aspects of rational insurance purchasing. Journal of Political Economy, 76, Mullainathan, Sendhil and Richard Thaler, (2001), Behavioral Economics. International Encyclopedia of Social Sciences, pp Pashigian, B. Peter, Schkade, Lawrence, and George Menefee, (1966). The selection of an optimal deductible for a given insurance policy. Journal of Business, 39, Schoemaker, Paul (1976). Experimental studies on individual decision making under risk: An Information processing approach. Doctoral dissertation, Univ. of Pennsylvania. Shapira, Zur.and Itzhak Venezia, (1999). Experimental tests of self selection and screening in insurance decisions. The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 24, Slovic, Paul et. al. (1977). Preference for insuring against probable small losses. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 53,

23 Tversky, Amos. and Kahneman, Daniel (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, (Summer 1999) Employee Benefits Survey: Technical Note. Compensation and Working Conditions, Viscusi, W. Kip and Richard Zeckhauser, (2006), National survey evidence on disasters and relief: Risk beliefs, self-interest, and compassion. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 33, Wakker, Peter., Thaler, Richard and Amos Tversky (1997). Probabilistic insurance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 15,

24 Table 1 Selling insurance Assume that you are an insurance agent. You were offered an opportunity of making a bid for insuring rental apartments through a large organization in the city (N=1000). Basically, if your bid is accepted you'll be able to sell policies to these 1000 employees (who will buy personal insurance from you) covering their personal belongings in the apartments they rent, against fire and theft. Assume that the probabilities of damages that these employees may incur (based on their previous insurance records) come from the following two distributions: A B Loss($) Probability Loss ( $) Probability You cannot know which distribution a particular employee "comes" from; the company told you that 75% of the employees "come" from distribution A and 25% from distribution B*. * In experiments 1 and 3, for about half of the subjects, the sentence read as above, for the other half the sentence said that 25% of the employees come from A and 75% from B. In experiment 2 we presented the subjects only with distribution A. 23

25 Table 1 (cont'd) What would be the prices you'd charge? Recall that there is competition (other agents can come with more attractive offers). At the same time, in setting the price of the policy you should not forget the potential claims. Expected claims are affected by the policy an employee buys as well as the distribution he "comes" from. Employees are free to choose between the offered policies and may also decide not to buy any policy. Please note that if you price the policy(ies) too high you may have no demand. On the other hand, if you price them too low you may eventually lose money. This potential deal is very important to you as insurance business is declining. Think and decide! Policy 1: A deductible of $100 Policy 2: A deductible of $0 Decision: Policy 1 Policy 2 sell/no sell at price $ each sell/no sell at price $ each Please explain your decision: 24

26 Table 2 Summary statistics of prices of policies of full coverage, (FC, D = 0), and deductible policies, (D =100), Experiment 1, Amateurs Panel A D=0 D=100 N (number of contracts) Average price (P) Maximum price Minimum price Standard deviation of prices Expected payments (E) EPR (P/E) Panel B Differences between the two types of policies Average difference in price P 75.9 Number Percentage of all subjects N ( P > D) 19 21% N ( P = D) 21 24% N ( P > D) 40 45% N (P D < E D ) 60 67% N (P FC < E FC ) 18 20% Notes: 1. P denotes the difference between the price determined for the full coverage policy, and for the policy with a deductible. 2. E denotes the difference between the expected payments by the insurer under the full coverage policy, and under the policy with a deductible. 3. N ( P > 100) denotes the number of subjects for whom P > N ( P = 100) denotes the number of subjects for whom P = N (P D < E D ) denotes the number of subjects who set a price for the deductible policy lower than the expected payments for this policy, E D. 6. N (P FC < E FC ) denotes the number of subjects who set the price of the full coverage policy lower than its expected value, E FC. 7. EPR is "Expected profitability Ratio" 25

27 Table 3 Summary statistics of prices of policies of full coverage, (FC, D = 0), and deductible policies, (Di =60, 120), Experiment 2, Amateurs (USA) Panel A Group 1 Group 2 D=0 D=60 D=0 D = 120 N (number of contracts) Average price (P) Maximum price Minimum price Std. Dev. prices Expected payments (E) EPR (P/E) Panel B Differences between the two types of policies (within each group) Group 1, D = 60 Group 2, D = 120 Average difference in price P Number Percentage of all subjects Number Percentage of all subjects N ( P > D) 1 4.8% % N ( P = D) % % N ( P > D) % % N (P D < E D ) % % N (P FC < E FC ) % % Notes: 1. P denotes the difference between the price determined for the full coverage policy, and for the policy with a deductible. 2. E denotes the difference between the expected payments by the insurer under the full coverage policy, and under the policy with a deductible. 3. N ( P > 100) denotes the number of subjects for whom P > N ( P = 100) denotes the number of subjects for whom P = N (P D < E D ) denotes the number of subjects determining a price for the deductible policy lower than the expected payments for this policy, E D. 6. N (P FC < E FC ) denotes the number of subjects determining the price of the full coverage policy lower than its expected value, E FC. 7. EPR is "Expected profitability Ratio" 26

28 Table 4 Summary statistics of prices of policies of full coverage, (FC, D = 0), and deductible policies, (D =100), Experiment 3, Professionals Panel A D=0 D=100 N (number of contracts) Average price (P) Maximum price Minimum price Standard deviation of prices Expected payments (E) EPR (P/E) Panel B Differences between the two types of policies D=0 D=100 Average difference in price, P 55.2 Number Percentage of all subjects N ( P > D) % N ( P = D) % N ( P > D) % N (P D < E D ) % N (P FC < E FC ) % Notes: 1. P denotes the difference between the price determined for the full coverage policy, and for the policy with a deductible. 2. E denotes the difference between the expected payments by the insurer under the full coverage policy, and under the policy with a deductible. 3. N ( P > 100) denotes the number of subjects for whom P > N ( P = 100) denotes the number of subjects for whom P = N (P D < E D ) denotes the number of subjects determining a price for the deductible policy lower than the expected payments for this policy, E D. 6. N (P FC < E FC ) denotes the number of subjects determining the price of the full coverage policy lower than its expected value, E FC. 7. EPR is "Expected profitability Ratio" 27

29 Table 5 Advertised prices for automobile insurance for Toyota Corolla 2004 Deductible Policy price No. of Students Choosing Percent of Students Choosing Note: All values are in $US. We converted the Israeli Shekels prices to $US according to the exchange rate (4.33IS = 1US$) that prevailed on the day the prices were published, December 28,

On the preference for full-coverage policies: Why do people buy too much insurance?

On the preference for full-coverage policies: Why do people buy too much insurance? Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Journal of Economic Psychology 29 (2008) 747 761 www.elsevier.com/locate/joep On the preference for full-coverage policies: Why do people buy too much insurance?

More information

The Demand for Disaster Insurance An Experimental Study. Chinn Ping Fan*

The Demand for Disaster Insurance An Experimental Study. Chinn Ping Fan* The Demand for Disaster Insurance An Experimental Study 本 文 發 表 於 25 兩 岸 經 濟 論 壇 : 產 業 經 濟 與 財 務 管 理 研 討 會, 25/4/18-19, 天 津, 南 開 大 學 Chinn Ping Fan* Many natural disasters have the characteristic of low

More information

Prospect Theory and the Demand for Insurance

Prospect Theory and the Demand for Insurance Prospect Theory and the emand for Insurance avid L. Eckles and Jacqueline Volkman Wise ecember 211 Abstract We examine the effect of prospect theory preferences on the demand for insurance to determine

More information

Insurance Demand and Prospect Theory. by Ulrich Schmidt

Insurance Demand and Prospect Theory. by Ulrich Schmidt Insurance Demand and Prospect Theory by Ulrich Schmidt No. 1750 January 2012 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Hindenburgufer 66, 24105 Kiel, Germany Kiel Working Paper No. 1750 January 2012 Insurance

More information

Reinsurance Reserving and the Insurance Cycle. Mike Rozema, SVP, Swiss Re CLRS 2011

Reinsurance Reserving and the Insurance Cycle. Mike Rozema, SVP, Swiss Re CLRS 2011 Reinsurance Reserving and the Insurance Cycle Mike Rozema, SVP, Swiss Re CLRS 2011 Agenda Scope and Introduction The Underwriting Cycle Data from Schedule P The Winner's Curse Cognitive Biases Optimism,

More information

Health Insurance & Behavioral Economics

Health Insurance & Behavioral Economics Health Insurance & Behavioral Economics Alan C. Monheit, Ph.D. Rutgers University School of Public Health Rutgers National Bureau of Economic Research Standard Model Underlying Consumer Choice In the standard

More information

INVESTORS DECISION TO TRADE STOCKS AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY. Sharon Shafran, Uri Ben-Zion and Tal Shavit. Discussion Paper No. 07-08.

INVESTORS DECISION TO TRADE STOCKS AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY. Sharon Shafran, Uri Ben-Zion and Tal Shavit. Discussion Paper No. 07-08. INVESTORS DECISION TO TRADE STOCKS AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY Sharon Shafran, Uri Ben-Zion and Tal Shavit Discussion Paper No. 07-08 July 2007 Monaster Center for Economic Research Ben-Gurion University of

More information

The Equity Premium in India

The Equity Premium in India The Equity Premium in India Rajnish Mehra University of California, Santa Barbara and National Bureau of Economic Research January 06 Prepared for the Oxford Companion to Economics in India edited by Kaushik

More information

Volatility: A Brief Overview

Volatility: A Brief Overview The Benefits of Systematically Selling Volatility July 2014 By Jeremy Berman Justin Frankel Co-Portfolio Managers of the RiverPark Structural Alpha Fund Abstract: A strategy of systematically selling volatility

More information

Thomas Russell. Dept. of Economics Santa Clara University

Thomas Russell. Dept. of Economics Santa Clara University Catastrophe Insurance and the Demand for Deductibles Thomas Russell Dept. of Economics Santa Clara University The author acknowledges the assistance of a Leavey Grant in the preparation of this paper.

More information

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013) Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013) Introduction The United States government is, to a rough approximation, an insurance company with an army. 1 That is

More information

Insurance Demand under Prospect Theory: A Graphical Analysis. by Ulrich Schmidt

Insurance Demand under Prospect Theory: A Graphical Analysis. by Ulrich Schmidt Insurance Demand under Prospect Theory: A Graphical Analysis by Ulrich Schmidt No. 1764 March 2012 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Hindenburgufer 66, 24105 Kiel, Germany Kiel Working Paper No. 1764

More information

Testimony for the ERISA Advisory Council on Ways to Help Participants Make Better Decisions in Risk-Transfer Transactions

Testimony for the ERISA Advisory Council on Ways to Help Participants Make Better Decisions in Risk-Transfer Transactions Testimony for the ERISA Advisory Council on Ways to Help Participants Make Better Decisions in Risk-Transfer Transactions by Erzo F.P. Luttmer, May 28, 2015 Executive Summary For most people, choosing

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk 1 This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. 1 Jonathan B. Berk Haas School

More information

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov).

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov). Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov). These payments are called premiums. Insurer promises to make a

More information

Eliminating Over-Confidence in Software Development Effort Estimates

Eliminating Over-Confidence in Software Development Effort Estimates Eliminating Over-Confidence in Software Development Effort Estimates Magne Jørgensen 1 and Kjetil Moløkken 1,2 1 Simula Research Laboratory, P.O.Box 134, 1325 Lysaker, Norway {magne.jorgensen, kjetilmo}@simula.no

More information

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions Chapter 7 Sealed-bid Auctions An auction is a procedure used for selling and buying items by offering them up for bid. Auctions are often used to sell objects that have a variable price (for example oil)

More information

Social Insurance (Chapter-12) Part-1

Social Insurance (Chapter-12) Part-1 (Chapter-12) Part-1 Background Dramatic change in the composition of government spending in the U.S. over time Background Social insurance programs: Government interventions in the provision of insurance

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley Word Count: 2,486 Definition Prospect Theory is a psychological account that describes how people make decisions under conditions of uncertainty. These may

More information

What Goes Up Must Come Down? Experimental Evidence on Intuitive Forecasting

What Goes Up Must Come Down? Experimental Evidence on Intuitive Forecasting What Goes Up Must Come Down? Experimental Evidence on Intuitive Forecasting BY JOHN BESHEARS, JAMES J. CHOI, ANDREAS FUSTER, DAVID LAIBSON, AND BRIGITTE C. MADRIAN Abstract: Do laboratory subjects correctly

More information

Investing on hope? Small Cap and Growth Investing!

Investing on hope? Small Cap and Growth Investing! Investing on hope? Small Cap and Growth Investing! Aswath Damodaran Aswath Damodaran! 1! Who is a growth investor?! The Conventional definition: An investor who buys high price earnings ratio stocks or

More information

UBS Global Asset Management has

UBS Global Asset Management has IIJ-130-STAUB.qxp 4/17/08 4:45 PM Page 1 RENATO STAUB is a senior assest allocation and risk analyst at UBS Global Asset Management in Zurich. renato.staub@ubs.com Deploying Alpha: A Strategy to Capture

More information

Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation

Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation Research Report Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation Psychological Science 22(6) 77 711 The Author(s) 11 Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalspermissions.nav

More information

Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna April 30, 2015 Outline 1. The Takeover Game 2. Hidden Type (Adverse Selection) 3. Empirical Economics: Intro 4. Empirical Economics: Home Insurance 5. Empirical

More information

New York University Stern School of Business Executive MBA Program in Management. Managerial Decision Making Spring 2005

New York University Stern School of Business Executive MBA Program in Management. Managerial Decision Making Spring 2005 New York University Stern School of Business Executive MBA Program in Management Managerial Decision Making Spring 2005 Professor Zur Shapira Office Hours: TBA Office: Tisch 7-06 Tel.: 998-0225 E mail:

More information

Chapter 12: Economics of Information

Chapter 12: Economics of Information Chapter 11: probs #1, #3, and #4, p. 298 Problem set 4: due week of Feb 20-24 Chapter 12: probs #1 a-b-c-d, #2, #3, pp. 320-321 Future problem sets Chapter 13: probs #1, #2 a-b-c-d, #3, #5, pp. 347-348

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

AN INTRODUCTION TO PREMIUM TREND

AN INTRODUCTION TO PREMIUM TREND AN INTRODUCTION TO PREMIUM TREND Burt D. Jones * February, 2002 Acknowledgement I would like to acknowledge the valuable assistance of Catherine Taylor, who was instrumental in the development of this

More information

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case Andrea Amelio and Dimitrios Magos ( 1 ) Introduction ( 1 ) This paper offers an economic background for the analysis conducted by the Commission during

More information

Introduction to Share Buyback Valuation

Introduction to Share Buyback Valuation By Magnus Erik Hvass Pedersen 1 Hvass Laboratories Report HL-1301 First edition January 1, 2013 This revision August 13, 2014 2 Please ensure you have downloaded the latest revision of this paper from

More information

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests 1 Why market efficiency matters.. Question of whether markets are efficient, and if not, where the inefficiencies lie, is central to investment valuation. If markets

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

PROCEEDINGS. May 20,21,22,23, 1973. EXPENSE ANALYSIS IN RATEMAKINCi AND PRICING ROGER C. WADE

PROCEEDINGS. May 20,21,22,23, 1973. EXPENSE ANALYSIS IN RATEMAKINCi AND PRICING ROGER C. WADE Volume LX, Part I No. 113 PROCEEDINGS May 20,21,22,23, 1973 EXPENSE ANALYSIS IN RATEMAKINCi AND PRICING ROGER C. WADE This paper analyres the traditional method of including non-loss expenses in property-liability

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET Wei T. Yue Alok R. Chaturvedi Shailendra Mehta Krannert Graduate School of Management Purdue University

More information

Inaction Inertia in the Stock Market 1

Inaction Inertia in the Stock Market 1 Inaction Inertia in the Stock Market 1 A ORIT TYKOCINSKI 2 AND RONI ISRAEL Department of Behavioral Sciences ABen Gurion University Beer-Sheva, Israel THANE S. PITTMAN Gettysburg College Based on the inaction

More information

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011. Two-State Options John Norstad j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011 Abstract How options are priced when the underlying asset has only two possible

More information

Final. Actuarial Standards Board. July 2011. Document 211070. Ce document est disponible en français 2011 Canadian Institute of Actuaries

Final. Actuarial Standards Board. July 2011. Document 211070. Ce document est disponible en français 2011 Canadian Institute of Actuaries Final Final Standards Standards of Practice for the Valuation of Insurance Contract Liabilities: Life and Health (Accident and Sickness) Insurance (Subsection 2350) Relating to Mortality Improvement (clean

More information

Anchoring Bias in Forecast Information Sharing in a Supply Chain

Anchoring Bias in Forecast Information Sharing in a Supply Chain Anchoring Bias in Forecast Information Sharing in a Supply Chain N. Karthikram R.K. Rajagopal G. Janarthanan RKAmit Abstract This paper investigates the behavioral aspects of decision making of retailers,

More information

Dynamic Inefficiencies in Insurance Markets: Evidence from long-term care insurance *

Dynamic Inefficiencies in Insurance Markets: Evidence from long-term care insurance * Dynamic Inefficiencies in Insurance Markets: Evidence from long-term care insurance * Amy Finkelstein Harvard University and NBER Kathleen McGarry University of California, Los Angeles and NBER Amir Sufi

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

Defined Contribution Plans for Passive Investors

Defined Contribution Plans for Passive Investors Defined Contribution Plans for Passive Investors by James Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian July 5, 2004 Executive summary 401(k) savers follow the path of least resistance Automatic enrollment

More information

Insurance Markets and Your Insurance Strategy By William C. Wood

Insurance Markets and Your Insurance Strategy By William C. Wood By William C. Wood Comparison shopping and insurance market competition are your friends as you put together an insurance strategy. A high degree of competition means that you will be able to choose from

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

Problem Set 9 Solutions

Problem Set 9 Solutions Problem Set 9 s 1. A monopoly insurance company provides accident insurance to two types of customers: low risk customers, for whom the probability of an accident is 0.25, and high risk customers, for

More information

Capital budgeting & risk

Capital budgeting & risk Capital budgeting & risk A reading prepared by Pamela Peterson Drake O U T L I N E 1. Introduction 2. Measurement of project risk 3. Incorporating risk in the capital budgeting decision 4. Assessment of

More information

How To Understand The Theory Of Active Portfolio Management

How To Understand The Theory Of Active Portfolio Management Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk Proponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible to beat the market consistently. In support of their

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Emilia Matei 1005056 EC372 Term Paper. Topic 3 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes and Merton method of modelling derivatives prices was first introduced

More information

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Emily Polito, Trinity College In the past two decades, there have been many empirical studies both in support of and opposing

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE COMPLAINT RATIOS

AN ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE COMPLAINT RATIOS AN ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE COMPLAINT RATIOS Richard L. Morris, College of Business, Winthrop University, Rock Hill, SC 29733, (803) 323-2684, morrisr@winthrop.edu, Glenn L. Wood, College of Business, Winthrop

More information

Annuity for micro pensions

Annuity for micro pensions Annuity for micro pensions Nadiya Ivanova January 2010 There are many elements in the design of a micro pension scheme that the pension provider needs to consider carefully. One of the most important decisions

More information

Innovation, Fads and Long-Term Value in Management Accounting

Innovation, Fads and Long-Term Value in Management Accounting Innovation, Fads and Long-Term Value in Management Accounting Joan Luft Michigan State University January 2006 Draft: Do not reproduce 1 Innovation Innovate or die, we are told. It's the core of excellence

More information

Stock Prices and Business Investment

Stock Prices and Business Investment Stock Prices and Business Investment BY YARON LEITNER I s there a link between the stock market and business investment? Empirical evidence indicates that there is. A firm tends to invest more when its

More information

Often stock is split to lower the price per share so it is more accessible to investors. The stock split is not taxable.

Often stock is split to lower the price per share so it is more accessible to investors. The stock split is not taxable. Reading: Chapter 8 Chapter 8. Stock: Introduction 1. Rights of stockholders 2. Cash dividends 3. Stock dividends 4. The stock split 5. Stock repurchases and liquidations 6. Preferred stock 7. Analysis

More information

The Cost of Capital, and a Note on Capitalization

The Cost of Capital, and a Note on Capitalization The Cost of Capital, and a Note on Capitalization Prepared by Kerry Krutilla 8all rights reserved Introduction Often in class we have presented a diagram like this: Table 1 B B1 B2 B3 C -Co This kind of

More information

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction Benjamin Edelman Hoan Soo Lee Working Paper 09-074 Copyright 2008 by Benjamin Edelman and Hoan Soo Lee Working papers are in draft form. This working paper

More information

Crop Tariff Models For Farmers Insurance

Crop Tariff Models For Farmers Insurance Rationality of Choices in Subsidized Crop Insurance Markets HONGLI FENG, IOWA STATE UNIVERSITY XIAODONG (SHELDON) DU, UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN-MADISON DAVID HENNESSY, IOWA STATE UNIVERSITY Plan of talk

More information

In this article, we go back to basics, but

In this article, we go back to basics, but Asset Allocation and Asset Location Decisions Revisited WILLIAM REICHENSTEIN WILLIAM REICHENSTEIN holds the Pat and Thomas R. Powers Chair in Investment Management at the Hankamer School of Business at

More information

EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE. Copyright 2005 by the Society of Actuaries

EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE. Copyright 2005 by the Society of Actuaries EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE OF THE SOCIET OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE by Judy Feldman Anderson, FSA and Robert L. Brown, FSA Copyright 25 by the Society of Actuaries The Education and Examination

More information

Warranty Designs and Brand Reputation Analysis in a Duopoly

Warranty Designs and Brand Reputation Analysis in a Duopoly Warranty Designs and Brand Reputation Analysis in a Duopoly Kunpeng Li * Sam Houston State University, Huntsville, TX, U.S.A. Qin Geng Kutztown University of Pennsylvania, Kutztown, PA, U.S.A. Bin Shao

More information

Competitive Bids and Post-Issuance Price Performance in the Municipal Bond Market. Daniel Bergstresser* Randolph Cohen**

Competitive Bids and Post-Issuance Price Performance in the Municipal Bond Market. Daniel Bergstresser* Randolph Cohen** Competitive Bids and Post-Issuance Price Performance in the Municipal Bond Market Daniel Bergstresser* Randolph Cohen** (March 2015. Comments welcome. Please do not cite or distribute without permission)

More information

EXTRAPOLATION BIAS: INSIDER TRADING IMPROVEMENT SIGNAL

EXTRAPOLATION BIAS: INSIDER TRADING IMPROVEMENT SIGNAL EXTRAPOLATION BIAS: INSIDER TRADING IMPROVEMENT SIGNAL HIGHLIGHTS Consistent with previous studies, we find that knowledge of insider trading is valuable to non-insider investors. We find that the change

More information

Excess Volatility and Closed-End Fund Discounts

Excess Volatility and Closed-End Fund Discounts Excess Volatility and Closed-End Fund Discounts Michael Bleaney School of Economics University of Nottingham Nottingham NG7 RD, U.K. Tel. (+44) 115 951 5464 Fax (+44) 115 951 4159 e-mail: michael.bleaney@nottingham.ac.uk

More information

Credit Lectures 26 and 27

Credit Lectures 26 and 27 Lectures 26 and 27 24 and 29 April 2014 Operation of the Market may not function smoothly 1. Costly/impossible to monitor exactly what s done with loan. Consumption? Production? Risky investment? Involuntary

More information

Using Behavioral Economics to Improve Diversification in 401(k) Plans: Solving the Company Stock Problem

Using Behavioral Economics to Improve Diversification in 401(k) Plans: Solving the Company Stock Problem Using Behavioral Economics to Improve Diversification in 401(k) Plans: Solving the Company Stock Problem Shlomo Benartzi The Anderson School at UCLA Richard H. Thaler The University of Chicago Investors

More information

11 Option. Payoffs and Option Strategies. Answers to Questions and Problems

11 Option. Payoffs and Option Strategies. Answers to Questions and Problems 11 Option Payoffs and Option Strategies Answers to Questions and Problems 1. Consider a call option with an exercise price of $80 and a cost of $5. Graph the profits and losses at expiration for various

More information

account statement a record of transactions in an account at a financial institution, usually provided each month

account statement a record of transactions in an account at a financial institution, usually provided each month GLOSSARY GLOSSARY Following are definitions for key words as they are used in the financial life skills resource. They may have different or additional meanings in other contexts. A account an arrangement

More information

Issues in Comparing Capitalization Rates for Leased Fee and Fee Simple Estates

Issues in Comparing Capitalization Rates for Leased Fee and Fee Simple Estates January 23, 2001 Issues in Comparing Capitalization Rates for Leased Fee and Fee Simple Estates Jeffrey D. Fisher, Ph.D. A. Scruggs Love, Jr., MAI, CRE There are three traditional approaches used by appraisers

More information

The Determinants of Used Rental Car Prices

The Determinants of Used Rental Car Prices Sung Jin Cho / Journal of Economic Research 10 (2005) 277 304 277 The Determinants of Used Rental Car Prices Sung Jin Cho 1 Hanyang University Received 23 August 2005; accepted 18 October 2005 Abstract

More information

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013 Insurance Michael Peters December 27, 2013 1 Introduction In this chapter, we study a very simple model of insurance using the ideas and concepts developed in the chapter on risk aversion. You may recall

More information

Indexed and Non-Indexed Insurance

Indexed and Non-Indexed Insurance The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 7 (No 24, July 1982), 264-275 Indexed and Non-Indexed Insurance by Yaffa Machnes * IntroductIon Inflation is usually defined as a substantial increase in the general

More information

Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection

Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection Adverse selection is said to occur if potential buyers of insurance know their own probabilities of loss better than do insurance companies. So suppose

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 213-23 August 19, 213 The Price of Stock and Bond Risk in Recoveries BY SIMON KWAN Investor aversion to risk varies over the course of the economic cycle. In the current recovery,

More information

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty 1. Introduction In this lecture we examine the theory of decision-making under uncertainty and its application to the demand for insurance. The undergraduate

More information

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk 3 Introduction to Assessing Risk Important Question. How do we assess the risk an investor faces when choosing among assets? In this discussion we examine how an investor would assess the risk associated

More information

Share buybacks have grown

Share buybacks have grown The forensics of share buybacks Companies are increasingly using share-buybacks but who wins and who gains from these transactions? CHRISTINE BROWN looks at the evidence. CHRISTINE BROWN Associate Professor

More information

Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products

Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products available 2. characteristics or relative qualities of

More information

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Alary D. Bien F. TSE (LERNA) University Paris Dauphine Abstract In this note, we consider an adverse selection problem

More information

Using Prospect Theory to Explain Anomalous Crop Insurance Coverage Choice. Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University. Abstract

Using Prospect Theory to Explain Anomalous Crop Insurance Coverage Choice. Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University. Abstract Using Prospect Theory to Explain Anomalous Crop Insurance Coverage Choice Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University Abstract Farmers decisions about how much crop insurance to buy are not generally consistent

More information

Chapter 18. Asymmetric Information. The buyer needs a hundred eyes, the seller not one. George Herbert (1651)

Chapter 18. Asymmetric Information. The buyer needs a hundred eyes, the seller not one. George Herbert (1651) Chapter 18 Asymmetric Information The buyer needs a hundred eyes, the seller not one. George Herbert (1651) Chapter 18 Outline 18.1 Problems Due to Asymmetric Information 18.2 Responses to Adverse Selection

More information

The Time Value of Money

The Time Value of Money The Time Value of Money This handout is an overview of the basic tools and concepts needed for this corporate nance course. Proofs and explanations are given in order to facilitate your understanding and

More information

Medigap Coverage for Prescription Drugs. Statement of Deborah J. Chollet, Senior Fellow Mathematica Policy Research, Inc.

Medigap Coverage for Prescription Drugs. Statement of Deborah J. Chollet, Senior Fellow Mathematica Policy Research, Inc. Medigap Coverage for Prescription Drugs Statement of Deborah J. Chollet, Senior Fellow Mathematica Policy Research, Inc. Washington, DC Testimony before the U.S. Senate Committee on Finance Finding the

More information

Behavioral Finance: Two Minds at Work

Behavioral Finance: Two Minds at Work Behavioral Finance in Action Behavioral Finance: Two Minds at Work Understand. Act. Decisive Insights for forwardlooking investment strategies Behavioral finance is an extension of behavioral economics,

More information

In this chapter, we build on the basic knowledge of how businesses

In this chapter, we build on the basic knowledge of how businesses 03-Seidman.qxd 5/15/04 11:52 AM Page 41 3 An Introduction to Business Financial Statements In this chapter, we build on the basic knowledge of how businesses are financed by looking at how firms organize

More information

Business Divorce, Valuation and the Importance of a Buy-Sell Agreement. by Gerald A. Shanker

Business Divorce, Valuation and the Importance of a Buy-Sell Agreement. by Gerald A. Shanker Business Divorce, Valuation and the Importance of a Buy-Sell Agreement by Gerald A. Shanker Business Divorce, Valuation and the Importance of a Buy-Sell Agreement by Gerald A. Shanker Buy-sell agreements

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Asymmetric Information in Competitive Markets

Asymmetric Information in Competitive Markets Chapter 22 Asymmetric Information in Competitive Markets In our treatment of externalities in Chapter 21, we introduced into our model for the first time an economic force (other than government-induced

More information

Behavioral Finance in Action

Behavioral Finance in Action Behavioral Finance in Action Psychological challenges in the financial advisor/ client relationship, and strategies to solve them Part 1 Introduction: Two Minds at Work By Shlomo Benartzi, Ph.D. Professor,

More information

Usefulness of expected values in liability valuation: the role of portfolio size

Usefulness of expected values in liability valuation: the role of portfolio size Abstract Usefulness of expected values in liability valuation: the role of portfolio size Gary Colbert University of Colorado Denver Dennis Murray University of Colorado Denver Robert Nieschwietz Seattle

More information

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas 0802869. Words: 3441

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas 0802869. Words: 3441 Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas 0802869 Words: 3441 1 1. Introduction In this paper I present Black, Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) (BSM) general

More information

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1,

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1, XVII. SECURITY PRICING AND SECURITY ANALYSIS IN AN EFFICIENT MARKET Consider the following somewhat simplified description of a typical analyst-investor's actions in making an investment decision. First,

More information

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis MS14/6.2: Annex 4 Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 November 2015 This annex describes data analysis we carried out to improve our understanding of switching and shopping around behaviour in the UK

More information

Comparing the performance of retail unit trusts and capital guaranteed notes

Comparing the performance of retail unit trusts and capital guaranteed notes WORKING PAPER Comparing the performance of retail unit trusts and capital guaranteed notes by Andrew Clare & Nick Motson 1 1 The authors are both members of Cass Business School s Centre for Asset Management

More information

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION, BACKGROUND, AND MOTIVATION. Over the last decades, risk analysis and corporate risk management activities have

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION, BACKGROUND, AND MOTIVATION. Over the last decades, risk analysis and corporate risk management activities have Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION, BACKGROUND, AND MOTIVATION 1.1 INTRODUCTION Over the last decades, risk analysis and corporate risk management activities have become very important elements for both financial

More information

Asymmetric Information

Asymmetric Information Chapter 12 Asymmetric Information CHAPTER SUMMARY In situations of asymmetric information, the allocation of resources will not be economically efficient. The asymmetry can be resolved directly through

More information

How to Win the Stock Market Game

How to Win the Stock Market Game How to Win the Stock Market Game 1 Developing Short-Term Stock Trading Strategies by Vladimir Daragan PART 1 Table of Contents 1. Introduction 2. Comparison of trading strategies 3. Return per trade 4.

More information

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information By: Michael Rothschild and Joseph Stiglitz Presented by Benjamin S. Barber IV, Xiaoshu Bei, Zhi Chen, Shaiobi

More information